NOTE TO SELF READ THESE

Basically just noting these articles to myself and anyone else who might be interested. Both were published over the last month. One of the recent past one on the rather distant past.

Three million Trotskyists? Explaining extreme left voting in France in the 2002 presidential election

In the first round of the 2002 French presidential election, three million voters (10.4 per cent of the national vote) supported Trotskyist candidates. This unprecedented electoral result has received little academic attention. This study aimed to identify the strongest socio-demographic and attitudinal predictors of support for the new extreme left in 2002. A multivariate framework was applied in a series of models, using data from the 2002 French Electoral Panel. The study also aimed to understand the rise of the Trotskyists in the context of broader social and political developments. The analysis was grounded in series of hypotheses constituting a model of class voting in postindustrial France. Overall, the analysis tended to confirm the predictions of the model, with younger voters at the lower end of the service sector being the most likely to support the three Trotskyist parties. With regard to attitudes, opposition to economic liberalism proved the strongest single predictor of Trotskyist voting, followed by liberal attitudes on cultural issues, political distrust and political disengagement. However, in terms of economic attitudes, Trotskyist voters still came out as surprisingly close to mainstream left voters. In conclusion, it is argued that models of class voting should reconsider the political role of social class in a postindustrial context, and pay particular attention to the trajectories of different classes over time in terms of changing employment conditions and life chances in order to understand how class is likely to shape party preferences.

Black man’s burden, white man’s welfare: control, devolution and development in the British Empire, 1880-1914

This article organizes an economic analysis of the effects of colonial rule on capital market access and development. Our insights provide an interpretation of institutional variance and growth performance across British colonies. We emphasize the degree of coercion available to British authorities in explaining alternative set-ups. White colonies, with a credible exit option, managed to secure a better deal than those where non-whites predominated, for which we find evidence of welfare losses.

SOME NEW RESEARCH ON THE EMPIRICAL DETERMINANTS OF STATE FRAGILITY

Graziella Bertocchi summarizes some of the recent work she has done with Andrea Guerzoni over at VOX.eu.

The causes and implications of state fragility – also known as state failure – are not yet well understood. This column explores the determinants of state fragility in sub-Saharan Africa and finds that institutions – as measured by civil liberties and the number of revolutions – are the main drivers. It says institutions trump economic, geographic, and historical factors.  

The interesting findings are:

We find that institutional variables are the key determinants of state fragility. The probability of a country having a fragile state decreases with the level of civil liberties and increases with the number of revolutions. Economic determinants such as per capita GDP growth and investment are not significant when we introduce standard controls for omitted variables. Geography is also insignificant while colonial history appears to be only marginally relevant. These conclusion hold after controlling for endogeneity with standard analytical tools.

She ends the article drawing conclusions regarding EU aid and how including an emphasis on social objective as well as economic ons might feed back into economic growth.

 Among the goals declared since the 1992 Maastricht Treaty, the EU emphasises international cooperation, with the objectives to foster and consolidate democracy, the rule of law, and respect for human rights and fundamental freedoms. Our findings suggest that pursuing these objectives may indeed complement economic aid to developing countries, since it implies that the EU should be interested in reducing of the likelihood of state fragility throughout the world, resulting in a positive impact on their aid absorption.

I’m pretty interested in this question of how social objectives facilitate economic growth. From my reading the evidence that they impede on economic growth is not as strong as some might suggest. I might come back to this in another post in a few days.

THINGS HEAT UP BETWEEN US AND CHINA OVER RENMINBI

The New Statesman reports that “The US Treasury is delaying a report on China’s manipulation of the yuan, which was due out on 15 April, by several months.” This has been a pretty big issue of policy debate within economics recently. China is quite clearly engaging in currency manipulation on a level never previously seen (as in never ever).  The US Treasury has a statutory obligation to publish a report every year (I think) that states which, if any, countries are engaging in currency manipulation. If the US government then gets a report saying that China is manipulating the value of its currency there would be a political obligation to do something about it. This hasn’t come to a head until recently because up until the recession it was seen as China financing the US deficit. But now its seen as China importing US demand and exporting Chinese savings at a time when the US government is trying to stimulate demand and when savings are already greater than investment.

Perhaps at the for front of the debate over the renminbi is Paul Krugman. He has written a lot on this recently and has given a very interesting an informative talk with Fred Bergsten of the Peterson Institute for International Economic. Essentially Krugman is calling for a 25% sanction on Chinese imports by the US in order to force China into revaluing its currency. The response has been impassioned. Business week reports:

Morgan Stanley Asia Chairman Stephen Roach said a “baseball bat” should be taken to economist Paul Krugman over his call for the U.S. to pressure China into allowing the yuan to appreciate.

Tyler Cowen at Marginal Revolution has said that Krugman current tirade shows that he is now neither an economist not a liberal! Krugman’s calls are also being heard in China where China Daily has been condemning Krugman’s call. The best commentary that I’ve seen that criticises Krugman’s argument is that of Yiping Huang, Professor of Economics at the China Center for Economic Research, Peking University, who has a detailed article over at VOX.eu. In that article Huang argues, as have others elsewhere, that if America goes on the offensive over the renminbi, it will only make it less likely that China will revalue. The idea here is that popular opinion will prevent the Chinese government from ‘giving in’ to America if America goes on the offensive, but that if this is done diplomatically China might revalue. I’m not too sure if I buy this argument for three reasons, 1. I don’t know how responsive the Chinese government is to public opinion, 2. a revaluation could actually benefit Chinese consumers as the renminbi would be stronger, and consumers would probably consume more and save less, resulting in a jump in living standards, 3. the US has been putting diplomatic pressure on China for years now to revalue and China simply hasn’t done it.

Anyway it’s worth listening to what Krugman is saying as, judging from the fact that the Treasury seems to be preparing a significant report, it now look like America might be about to go on the offensive. Krugmanwrites:

The renminbi thing isn’t at all hard to explain — it’s just supply and demand. Here:

DESCRIPTION

The more depreciated China’s exchange rate — the higher the price of the dollar in yuan* — the more dollars China earns from exports, and the fewer dollars it spends on imports. (Capital flows complicate the story a bit, but don’t change it in any fundamental way). By keeping its current artificially weak — a higher price of dollars in terms of yuan — China generates a dollar surplus; this means that the Chinese government has to buy up the excess dollars. There’s nothing arcane about it.

Nor is there anything arcane about the implications: In the current environment, with high unemployment around the world and policy interest rates as low as they can go, this is a predatory, beggar-thy-neighbor policy.

In another post Krugman extends his argument:

By creating an artificial capital account deficit, China is, as a matter of arithmetic necessity, creating an artificial current account surplus. And by doing that, it is exporting savings to the rest of the world.

In normal times, you could argue that this policy provides benefits to the rest of the world, by reducing borrowing costs (although given what we did with those capital inflows, maybe not). But these aren’t normal times. We’re currently living in a world in which both central banks and governments are unable or unwilling to pursue sufficiently expansionary policies to eliminate mass unemployment; so it’s a paradox of thrift world, in which anyone who tries to save more reduces demand, reduces employment, and – because investment responds to excess capacity – ends up actually reducing investment. By exporting savings to the rest of the world, via an artificial current account surplus, China is making all of us poorer….

… it’s a mistake to focus only on direct China versus America competition. In many cases, Chinese exports compete with those of other developing nations. If the renminbi rises, those nations would become more competitive – and would also find their currencies appreciating against the dollar, offering new channels for onshoring. This may sound speculative, but it isn’t: remember, if China ends its artificial export of capital, that has to show up in trade flows one way or another.

In the same post he explains how he sees the confrontation playing out:

Here’s how the initial phases of a confrontation would play out – this is actually Fred Bergsten’s scenario, and I think he’s right. First, the United States declares that China is a currency manipulator, and demands that China stop its massive intervention. If China refuses, the United States imposes a countervailing duty on Chinese exports, say 25 percent. The EU quickly follows suit, arguing that if it doesn’t, China’s surplus will be diverted to Europe. I don’t know what Japan does.

Suppose that China then digs in its heels, and refuses to budge. From the US-EU point of view, that’s OK! The problem is China’s surplus, not the value of the renminbi per se – and countervailing duties will do much of the job of eliminating that surplus, even if China refuses to move the exchange rate.

And precisely because the United States can get what it wants whatever China does, the odds are that China would soon give in.

Look, I know that many economists have a visceral dislike for this kind of confrontational policy. But you have to bear in mind that the really outlandish actor here is China: never before in history has a nation followed this drastic a mercantilist policy. And for those who counsel patience, arguing that China can eventually be brought around: the acute damage from China’s currency policy is happening now, while the world is still in a liquidity trap. Getting China to rethink that policy years from now, when (one can hope) advanced economies have returned to more or less full employment, is worth very little.

Obviously there are a number of interesting things in here. The argument that a revaluation would benefit other Asian exporters is one I find pretty interesting but not necessarily one I’m convinced of. That said I’ve seen very little, with the exception of Huang’s article linked above, that is in anyway persuasive that Krugman is wrong. And with the being a strong appetite in Congress for taking on China (130 members of Congress signed a letter to Timothy Geithner, Treasury secretary, and Gary Locke, commerce secretary, calling for action of China’s currency manipulation. Text of the letter here), it is well worth watching how this develops.

LAW SAYS SHAREHOLDERS DON`T OWN CORPORATIONS!

There`s an interesting article in the current edition of Harvard Business Review entitled “The Myth of Shareholder Capitalism”. In it the authors, Loizos Heracleous and Luh Luh Lan, state

Oddly, no previous management research has looked at what the legal literature says about the topic, so we conducted a systematic analysis of a century’s worth of legal theory and precedent. It turns out that the law provides a surprisingly clear answer: Shareholders do not own the corporation, which is an autonomous legal person. What’s more, when directors go against shareholder wishes—even when a loss in value is documented—courts side with directors the vast majority of the time. Shareholders seem to get this. They’ve tried to unseat directors through lawsuits just 24 times in large corporations over the past 20 years; they’ve succeeded only eight times. In short, directors are to a great extent autonomous. 

And yet, in an important 2007 article in the Journal of Business Ethics, 31 of 34 directors surveyed (each of whom served on an average of six Fortune 200 boards) said they’d cut down a mature forest or release a dangerous, unregulated toxin into the environment in order to increase profits. Whatever they could legally do to maximize shareholder wealth, they believed it was their duty to do.

There`s two pretty interesting things here. Firstly that “Shareholders do not own the corporation, which is an autonomous legal person”. I suppose intuitively this makes sense. We all know, from watching The Corporationif nothing else, that corporations have legal personality. And although a lot of lefties make a really big deal out of this, I`ve never heard anyone point out the flip-side which is that as Corporations have a legal responsibility in and of themselves, it is not legally justified to act solely in the interests of the shareholders. (If this is legally wrong, I appreciate someone pointing it out).

 The other interesting thing is the rather shocking finding in the Journal of Business Ethics. I hadn`t come across that before.

POLL SAYS 1/4 OF US REPUBLICANS THINK OBAMA “MAY BE THE ANTI-CHRIST”

I’m not sure if this says something negative about humanity, America, the American Right or polling as a methodology, but, as the Telegraphreports, 24% of American republicans think Obama “may be the anti-Christ”. The full details are over here. The poll seems to have been conducted in connection with the publication of some book, which might raise methodological questions. Nevertheless, one of the pollsters explains that when he saw the poll results:

he was “flabbergasted. I would’ve guessed the numbers would’ve been a lot smaller than that.” 

He added, “It means that very large numbers of people are misninformed not only about President Obama but many things in modern life.”

Its a funny world we live in.

ACADEMICS CONDEMN WILLIE WALSH

A rather encouraging albeit unusual letter has been published in today’s Guardian. It was signed many if not most of the UK’s top Industrial Relations academics. The body of the letter is

Dear Editor,

As academics in the field of employment relations our expertise includes the analysis of the causes, process and outcomes of industrial disputes and particularly the dynamics of strike action. Given the near certainty of further strikes (Follow-up strike will go ahead says union, March 22nd), it is clear to us that the actions of the chief executive of British Airways, notwithstanding his protestations to the contrary, are explicable only by the desire to break the union which represents the cabin crew. What other possible interpretation can there be forWillie Walsh rejecting Unite’s acceptance of BA’s previous offer or indeed of his marshalling of resources, including those of bitter industry rival Ryanair, to undermine the action of his staff? Walsh and now Prime Minister Brown have made the error of underestimating the deep seated and justifiable anger of a loyal and dedicated workforce, whose continued trust and goodwill is a vital ingredient of customer care.

Overwhelming majorities in two strike ballots in the face of tabloid opprobrium testify to employees’ understanding that a victory for Walsh’s macho management strategy would precipitate a race to the bottom in terms of working conditions and job quality. In the process, this would damage beyond repair the high standards of customer service for which BA cabin crew are renowned. The wider significance of a triumph of unilateral management prerogative would be a widening of the representation gap in UK employment relations, and a further erosion of worker rights and of that most precious of commodities – democracy. For all these reasons, BA’s cabin crew and their union, Unite, deserve our support rather than knee-jerk vilification.

I haven’t included the list of signatures but it’s well worth a look.

IMPLOSION OF THE GOP

Something not particularly relevant for us over here in the EU,* but still pretty interesting is the implosion of the US Republican party. I’ve been following it a little bit via the blogosphere etc. and the sole voice of reason,  a kind of Ken Clarke of the GOP today has been David Frum. (One difference being that Frum doesn’t seem to have anywhere near the same level of support as Clarke did.) Frum has however just recently being fired by the American Enterprise Institute. Bruce Barlett another Republican exile has a post lamenting this over here. *Rereading this post I just realised that this is the first time I’ve ever used the phrase ‘here in the EU’

YOU CAN STILL BUY VOTES IN IRELAND

I had a quick look over “Incumbent and Challenger Campaign Spending Effects in Proportional Electoral Systems: The Irish Elections of 2002” by Kenneth Benoit and Michael Marsh in the current issue of Political Research Quarterly. It seems kind of interesting and thought I’d flag it up. Here’s the abstract:

Positive effects of campaign spending on electoral outcomes have been found in several comparative, multiparty contexts, but very few of these systems use proportional representation. The few studies examining spending effects in multiparty elections have found that incumbent spending is no less effective than challenger spending, contrary to the vast bulk of empiricalliterature drawn from single-member district contexts. This study reexamines incumbent—challenger differences in spending effects under the single transferable vote. Examining the Irish general elections of 2002, the authors find a positive and statisticallysignificant relationship between spending and votes. Candidates that spend more win more votes, and outspending one’s rivals means winning more of the vote share. Spending more also directly increases a candidate’s chance of winning a seat. Finally, incumbent spending is considerably less effective thanspending by challengers from other parties but no less effective than spending by challengers from a candidate’s own party.

KRUGMAN AND OTHERS ON DEBT

Yet another great post by Paul Krugman on the significance of rising debt levels. First here’s the image that went with the post:

And now the post itself:

Earlier this week I gave a talk about the state of the crisis at Princeton’s Plasma Physics Lab, and one audience member asked a really good question: if the problem is that interest rates are at the zero lower bound, why should we worry about government borrowing? After all, doesn’t that mean that the government can borrow at a zero rate?

Now, part of the answer is that you really don’t want governments financing themselves largely with very short-term debt — that makes them too vulnerable to liquidity crises. But even long-term rates are low — the real interest rate on 10-year bonds is below 1.5 percent.

And if you do the arithmetic of debt service, that really does seem to suggest that debt isn’t a problem. To stabilize the real value of debt, all the government has to do is pay the real interest on it. So suppose that we add debt equal to 100 percent of GDP, which is much more than currently projected; servicing that debt should cost only 1.4 percent of GDP, or 7 percent of federal spending. Why should that be intolerable?

And even that, you could argue, is too pessimistic. To stabilize the debt/GDP ratio, all you need is to pay r-g, where r is the real interest rate and g the economy’s real growth rate; and right now r-g looks, ahem, negative.

And this benign view of debt isn’t just hypothetical: countries have, in reality, run up immense debt/GDP ratios without going insolvent: see the history of Britain, above.

So what’s the problem? Confidence. If bond investors start to lose confidence in a country’s eventual willingness to run even the small primary surpluses needed to service a large debt, they’ll demand higher rates, which requires much larger primary surpluses, and you can go into a death spiral.

So what determines confidence? The actual level of debt has some influence — but it’s not as if there’s a red line, where you cross 90 or 100 percent of GDP and kablooie; see the chart above. Instead, it has a lot to do with the perceived responsibility of the political elite.

What this means is that if you’re worried about the US fiscal position, you should not be focused on this year’s deficit, let alone the 0.07% of GDP in unemployment benefits Bunning tried to stop. You should, instead, worry about when investors will lose confidence in a country where one party insists both that raising taxes is anathema and that trying to rein in Medicare spending means creating death panels.

This is important. In particular given what is being said by the likes of George Osborne:

No one doubts that there were massive failures of financial regulation over the last decade.

No one seriously defends the fiscal rules, once spelt out in a Mais Lecture like this, which proved unable to prevent the Government running a budget deficit at the peak of the boom.

But we will not draw all the right lessons for the future unless we understand the deep macroeconomic roots of the crisis.

Much has already been written about what went wrong.  Much more is yet to be written.

Perhaps the most significant contribution to our understanding of the origins of the crisis has been made by Professor Ken Rogoff, former Chief Economist at the IMF, and his co-author Carmen Reinhart.

In a series of papers and now a book, they have demonstrated in exhaustive historical and statistical detail that while it always seems in the heat of the crisis that ‘this time is different’, the truth is that it almost never is.

As Rogoff and Reinhart demonstrate convincingly, all financial crises ultimately have their origins in one thing – rapid and unsustainable increases in debt.

As they write, “if there is one common theme… it is that excessive debt accumulation, whether it be by the government, banks, corporations, or consumers, often poses greater systemic risks that it seems during a boom.”

So while the specific financial innovations and failures of regulation that contributed to the credit crunch were new, the underlying macroeconomic warning signs were depressingly familiar from many dozens of crises in the past.

In this context, all the signals were flashing red for the UK economy: a rapid increase in household and bank balance sheets, soaring asset prices, a persistent current account deficit, and a structural budget deficit even at the peak of the boom.

Our banks became more leveraged than American banks, and our households became more indebted than any other major economy in history.

And in the aftermath of the crisis our public debt has risen more rapidly than any other major economy.

So while private sector debt was the cause of this crisis, public sector debt is likely to be the cause of the next one.

As Ken Rogoff himself puts it, “there’s no question that the most significant vulnerability as we emerge from recession is the soaring government debt. It’s very likely that will trigger the next crisis as governments have been stretched so wide.”

The latest research suggests that once debt reaches more than about 90% of GDP the risks of a large negative impact on long term growth become highly significant.

As is clear, Krugman is refering to the now bandied around figure that once debt goes over 90% trouble arises. But as is even clearer from the graph above, this simply doesn’t apply when there is confidence that this debt will get paid off. So where does this figure come from. Essentially it has arisen from the very impressive work of Reinhart and Rogoff. I read Reinhart and Rogoff’s book and that 90% figure didn’t jump out that strongly, nor did the book seem to give strong support for the Conservative/Fianna Fail commitment to cuts regardless of consequence. So I was a bit surprised when I say Ken Rogoff name onthat letter to the Sunday Times, which ostensibly supported Osborne’s proposals.

I think I was right to be surprised given that Reinhart and Rogoff wrote an article for the FT at the end of January arguing that:

Given these risks of higher government debt, how quickly should governments exit from fiscal stimulus? This is not an easy task, especially given weak employment, which is again quite characteristic of the post-second world war financial crises suffered by the Nordic countries, Japan, Spain and many emerging markets. Given the likelihood of continued weak consumption growth in the US and Europe, rapid withdrawal of stimulus could easily tilt the economy back into recession.

And given that Reinhart and Rogoff’s work is being used by the likes of Martin Wolf to argue in favour of continued stimulous. Wolf points out that Reinhart and Rogoff have shown that you the debt almost alwaysincreases during a recession:

In their work on the history of financial crises, Carmen Reinhart of the University of Maryland and Kenneth Rogoff of Harvard University note that “the real stock of debt nearly doubles” in crisis-hit countries.*

Perhap’s as  leftfootforward argues the letter to the Sunday Times actually was not in support of Osborne. The letter does state that

The exact timing of measures should be sensitive to developments in the economy, particularly the fragility of the recovery.

Regardless, not to disparage Ken Rogoff, but as Osborne is clearly arguing from autority here. ‘If the former chief economist of the IMF says it is must be true.’ He should perhaps listen to a former chief economist of the World Bank who recently gave his opinion of Osborne’s policies:

On the suggestion, put about by George Osborne, among others, that Britain is at risk of default: “I say you’re crazy — economically you clearly have the capacity to pay. The debt situation has been worse in other countries at other times. This is all scaremongering, perhaps linked to politics, perhaps rigged to an economic agenda, but it’s out of touch with reality. One of the advantages that you have is that you have your own central bank that can buy some of these bonds to stabilise their price.”